Abstract
In this paper, we present a multidimensional fuzzy analysis of the levels and the patterns of poverty and social fragility of migrants’ families, in the Italian region of Lombardy, in year 2014. Migrants’ poverty emerges as a complex trait, better described as a stratification of nuanced patterns than in black and white terms; Lombard migrants are in fact affected, to different extents, by “a diffused sharing of deprivation facets” and cannot be trivially split into deprived and non-deprived. The paper employs innovative data analysis tools from the Theory of Partially Ordered Sets; compared to mainstream monetary approaches, this leads to more realistic estimates of poverty diffusion and eliminates some well-known biases of standard evaluation procedures, providing strong support to the use of partial order concepts and tools in social evaluation studies.





Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
The terms “poverty” and “deprivation” are, in principle, not equivalent; the first may globally refer to monetary, material, relational and subjective problems or suffering, while the second refers more specifically to material aspects (“material deprivation”). However, in this paper, we use them interchangeably, to ease the reading and given that the attributes considered in the study, directly or indirectly, have to do with migrants’ economic capabilities.
For Italy, the National Institute of Statistics (ISTAT) estimates the relative poverty based on a poverty line (International Standard of Poverty Line—ISPL) defining as poor a family of two components with a consumption expenditure level lower or equal to the mean per-capita consumption expenditure. To define the relative poverty line for different family sizes, the Carbonaro equivalence scale, that assigns a unitary weight to a two-member family, is used.
ORIM stands for “Osservatorio regionale per l’integrazione e la multietnicità?” (“Regional observatory on integration and multietnicity”).
The overall response rate for each question is quite high. The only exception is the family income question with nearly \(22\%\) of missing information.
Let \(x_L\) and \(x_H\) be the distributions of x in the half population with lower and higher x scores respectively, \(\mu (x)\) be the arithmetic mean of x, \(\mu _{L}(x)\) and \(\mu _{H}(x)\) be the arithmetic means of \(x_L\) and \(x_H\), then \(G_B(x)=(\mu _{H}(x)-\mu _{L}(x))/4\mu (x)\) and \(G_W(x)=[G(x_L)\mu _L(x)/\mu (x)+G(x_H)\mu _H(x)/\mu (x)]/4\), where G(x) is the Gini coefficient (Yalonetzky 2016).
To apply such a traditional monetary procedure to the ORIM 2014 data, the poverty line for a two-member family has been set to the mean Italian per-capita income, according to the estimate of Bank of Italy for year 2014 (2015); poverty lines for families with a different number of members have been computed according to the equivalence scale reported in Table 1.
The selection of \(\pi _{\ell }\) and \(\pi _{u}\) must satisfy a consistency condition, which basically states that the two thresholds must imply each other. In the original posetic procedure (Fattore 2016), the upper threshold is univocally defined based on the lower one, so as to meet the consistency condition, by construction. Here, instead, we set the two thresholds independently, apparently violating the consistency requirement. In "Appendix 2", we show how the evaluation procedure has been slightly modified, so as to restore the required condition. This represents a non-trivial methodological improvement, which makes the evaluation procedure more flexible and effective.
References
Aaberge, R., Andersen, A. S., & Wennemo, T. (1999). Extent, level and distribution of low income in Norway 1979 1995. In B. Gustafsson & P. J. Pedersen (Eds.), Poverty and low income in the nordic countries (pp. 131–168). Vermont: Ashgate.
Alkire, S., & Foster, J. (2011). Counting and multidimensional poverty measurement. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7–8), 476–487.
Annoni, P., & Bruggemann, R. (2009). Exploring partial order of European Countries. Social Indicators Research, 92, 471–487.
Annoni, P., Fattore, M., & Bruggemann, R. (2011). A multi-criteria fuzzy approach for analyzing poverty structure (pp. 7–30). Statistica & Applicazioni (Special Issue).
Arcagni, A., & Fattore, M. (2014). PARSEC: An R package for poset-based evaluation of multidimensional poverty. In R. Bruggemann, L. Carlsen, & J. Wittmann (Eds.), Multi-indicator systems and modelling in partial order. Berlin: Springer.
Badinger, H., & Reuter, W. H. (2015). Measurement of fiscal rules: introducing the application of partially ordered set (POSET) theory. Journal of Macroeconomics, 43, 108–123.
Baio, G., Blangiardo, G. C., & Blangiardo, M. (2011). Centre Sampling Technique in Foreign Migration Surveys: aMethodological Note. Journal of Official Statistics, 27(3), 451–465.
Bank of Italy. (2015). Supplementi al bollettino statistico. Indagini campionarie. I bilanci nelle famiglie Italiane nellanno 2014. Year XXV(64).
Barbiano di Belgiojoso, E., & Rimoldi, S. (2005). Povertá e immigrazione straniera: resoconto dellesperienza di unindagine pilota nella realtá lombarda. In G. Rovati (Ed.), Le dimensioni della povertá. Strumenti di misura e politiche. Roma: Carocci.
Barbiano di Belgiojoso, E., Chelli, F. M., & Paterno, A. (2009). Povertá e standard di vita della popolazione straniera in Lombardia [Poverty and living standard of foreign population in Lombardy Region]. Rivista Italiana diEconomia, Demografia e Statistica, LXIII, 3(4), 23–30.
Bárcena-Martìn, E., & Pérez-Moreno, S. (2016). Immigrant-native gap in poverty: A cross-national European perspective. Review of Economics of the Household. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-015-9321-x (published online).
Berti, F., D’Agostino, A., Lemmi, A., & Neri, A. (2014). Poverty and deprivation of migrants versus natives in Italy. International Journal of Social Economics, 41(8), 630–649.
Blangiardo, G. C. (2008). (Ed.). L’immigrazione straniera in Lombardia. La settima indagine regionale. Rapporto 2007. Milano: ISMU-ORIM.
Blume, K., Gustafsson, B., Pedersen, P. J., & Verner, M. (2003). A tale of two countries: Poverty among migrants in Denmark and Sweden since 1984. UNU/WIDER Discussion Paper, 2003/36.
Blume, K., Gustafsson, B., Pedersen, P. J., & Verner, M. (2007). At the lower end of the table: Determinants of poverty among migrants to Denmark and Sweden. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 33(3), 373–396.
Busetta, A. (2016). Foreigners in Italy: Economic living conditions and unmet medical needs. Genus, 71, 2–3.
Carlsen, L. (2015). An alternative view on distribution keys for the possible relocation of refugees in the European Union. Social indicators research, 130, 1147–1163.
Carlsen, L., & Bruggemann, R. (2016). Fragile State Index: Trends and developments. A partial order data analysis. Social indicators research, 133(1), 1–14.
Constant, A., Roberts, R., & Zimmermann, K. (2009). Ethnic identity and immigrant homeownership. Urban Studies, 46(9), 1879–1898.
Curatolo, S., & Wolleb, G. (2010). Income vulnerability in Europe. In C. Ranci (Ed.), Social vulnerability in Europe. The new configuration of social risk. Chipenham and Eastbourne: Palgrave Macmillan.
Davidov, E., & Weick, S. (2011). Transition to homeownership among immigrant groups and natives in West Germany, 1984–2008. Journal of Immigrant & Refugee Studies, 9(4), 393–415.
de Carvalho, I. S. F. P. (2016). Poverty and precarity in Portugal: A multidimensional approach (Doctoral dissertation, NOVA School of Business and Economics).
della Queva, S. (2017). Analysis of social participation: A multidimensional approach based on the theory of partial ordering. In M. Fattore & R. Bruggemann (Eds.), Partial order concepts in applied sciences. Berlin: Springer.
di Bella, E., Gandullia, L., Leporatti, L., & Orcamo, P. (2016). Ranking and prioritization of emergency departments based on multi-indicator systems. Social Indicators Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1537-5.
Di Brisco, A. M., & Farina, P. (2017). Measuring Gender Gap from a Poset Perspective. Social Indicators Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-017-1582-8.
Diana, P., & Strozza, S. (2014). Strategie abitative degli immigrati nel casertano: la costruzione di una tipologia. In P. Donadio, G. Gabrielli, & M. Massari (Eds.), Uno come te. Europei e nuovi europei nei percorsi di integrazione (pp. 262–279). Milano: Franco Angeli.
Fattore, M., Bruggemann, R., & Owsiński, J. (2011). Using poset theory to compare fuzzy multidimensional material deprivation across regions. In S. Ingrassia, R. Rocci, & M. Vichi (Eds.), New Perspectives in statistical modeling and data analysis. Berlin: Springer.
Fattore, M., Maggino, F., & Colombo E. (2012). From composite indicators to partial order: Evaluating socio-economic phenomena through ordinal data. In F. Maggino & G. Nuvolati (Eds.), Quality of life in Italy: Research and reflections. Social Indicators Research Series 48. New York: Springer.
Fattore, M., & Maggino, F. (2014). Partial orders in socio-economics: A practical challenge for poset theorists or a cultural challenge for social scientists? In R. Bruggemann, L. Carlsen, & J. Wittmann (Eds.), Multi-indicator systems and modelling in partial order. Berlin: Springer.
Fattore, M., & Maggino, F. (2015). A new method for measuring and analyzing suffering—Comparing suffering patterns in Italian society. In R. E. Anderson (Ed.), World Suffering and the Quality of Life. New York: Springer.
Fattore, M. (2016). Partially ordered sets and the measurement of multidimensional ordinal deprivation. Social Indicators Research, 128(2), 835–858.
Fattore, M., & Arcagni, A. (2016). A reduced posetic approach to the measurement of multidimensional ordinal deprivation. Social Indicators Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1501-4.
Fellini, I., & Migliavacca, M. (2010). Unstable employment in Western Europe: Exploring the individual and household dimensions. In C. Ranci (Ed.), Social vulnerability in Europe. The new configuration of social risk. Chippenham and Eastbourne: Palgrave Macmillan.
Fernades, A., & Pereira, M. J. (2009). Health and migration in the European Union: Better health for all in an inclusive society. London: Pro-book, Publishing Limited.
Fleury, D. (2007). A study of poverty and working poverty among recent migrants in Canada. Human Resources and Social Development Canada: Human Resources and Social Development Canada (Final report Ottawa).
Galloway, T. A., & Aaberge, R. (2005). Assimilation effects on poverty among migrants in Norway. Journal of Population Economics, 18(4), 691–718.
Giannoni, M. (2010). Migrants inequalities in unmet needs for access to health care in Italy. In Paper presented at the 15th Aies conference, Moncalieri, Italy.
Gobillon, L., & Solignac, M. (2015). Homeownership of migrants in France: Selection effects related to international migration flows, Discussion Paper 9517. Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).
Hansen, J., & Lofstrom, M. (2003). Immigrant assimilation and welfare participation do migrants assimilate into or out of welfare? Journal of Human Resources, 38(1), 74–98.
Hansen, J., & Wahlberg, R. (2009). Poverty and its persistence: A comparison of natives and migrants in Sweden. Review of the Economics of the Household, 7, 105–132.
Hulle, Van M. M. (2012). Self-organizing maps. In G. Rozenberg, T. Bäck, & J. N. Kok (Eds.), Handbook of natural computing. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer.
Iglesias, K., Suter, C., Beycan, T., & Vani, B. P. (2016). Exploring multidimensional well-being in Switzerland: Comparing three synthesizing approaches. Social Indicators Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1452-9 (published online).
Istat. (2011). I redditi delle famiglie con stranieri. Anno 2008–2009. Statistiche report.
Istat. (2007, 2015). Resident Municipal Population by age, sex and marital status. http://dati.istat.it.
Istat. (2008, 2016). Poverty new series. http://dati.istat.it.
Kazemipur, A., & Halli, S. S. (2001). Migrants and ’New Poverty’: The case of Canada. International Migration Review, 35(4), 1129–1156.
Kim, J., & Tebaldi, E. (2011). The migrants’ odds to sleep into poverty: Double Jeopardy? Eastern Economic Journal, 37, 530–552.
Kohonen, T. (2001). Self-organizing maps. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer.
Kohonen, T. (2013). Essentials of the self organizing map. Neural Networks, 37, 52–65.
Koolman, X. (2007). Unmet need for health care in Europe, in EUROSTAT, Comparative EU statistics on income and living conditions: Issues and challenges. In Proceedings of the EU-SILC Conference (pp. 181–191).
Kosny, M., & Yalonetxky, G. (2016). Relative p-bipolarisation measurement with generalised means and hybrid Lorenz curve. Ecineq Working Paper Series, 404.
Koutsampelas, C. (2015). Blind spots of traditional poverty measurement: The case of migrants. Migration Letters, 12(2), 103–112.
Lelkes, O. (2007). Poverty among migrants in Europe. Policy Brief April 2007. Vienna: European Centre for Social Welfare Policy and Research.
Lemmi, A., Berti, F., Betti, G., D’Agostino, A., Gagliardi, F., Gambacorta, et al. (2013). Povertà e deprivazione. In C. Saraceno, N. Sartor, & G. Sciortino (Eds.), Stranieri e disuguali (pp. 149–174). Bologna: Il Mulino.
Lie, B. (2002). Immigration and immigrants (pp. 1–113). Statistical Analyses 54, Statistics Norway, Norway.
Lucchini, M., & Assi, J. (2013). Mapping patterns of multiple deprivation and well-being using self-organizing maps: An application to Swiss Household Panel Data. Social Indicators Research, 112(1), 129–149.
Muñozoz de Bustillo, R., & Anton, J. I. (2011). From rags to riches? Immigration and poverty in Spain. Population Research and Policy Review, 30, 661–676.
Myers, D., & Lee, S. W. (1998). Immigrant trajectories into home ownership: A temporal analysis of residential assimilation. International Migration Review, 32(3), 593–625.
Obućina, O. (2014). Paths into and out of poverty among migrants in Sweeden. Acta Sociologica, 57(1), 5–23.
Pastor, M. (2014). Stepping stone or sink hole? Migrants, poverty, and the future of Metropolitan America. In Conference paper, innovating to end urban poverty conference, March 27–28, University of Southern California, Los Angeles.
Pemberton, S., Phillimore, J., & Robinson, D. (2014). Causes and experiences of poverty among economic migrants in the UK. IRiS Working Paper Series, 4, University of Birmingham.
R Core Team. (2016). R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. Vienna: R Foundation for Statistical Computing. http://www.R-project.org/.
Raphael, E., & Smolensky, E. (2009). Immigration and poverty in the United States. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 44(2), 41–44.
Rimoldi, S. M. L., & Barbiano di Belgiojoso, E. (2016). Poor migrants! Evidence from the Italian Case. Athens Journal of Social Sciences, 3(2), 99–112.
Ripley, B. D. (1996). Pattern recognition and neural networks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Robinson, R., Reeve, K., & Casey, R. (2007). The housing pathways to migrants. York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation.
Serrano, Sanguilinda I., Barbiano di Belgiojoso, E., & González Ferrer A., & Rimoldi S. M. L., & Blangiardo G. C., (2017). Surveying immigrants in Southern Europe: Spanish and Italian strategies in comparative perspective. Comparative Migration Studies, 5, 17. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40878-017-0060-4.
Sullivan, D. H., & Ziegert, A. L. (2008). Hispanic immigrant poverty: Does ethnic origin matter? Population Research and Policy Review, 27(6), 667.
Yalonetzky, G. (2016). The necessary requirement of median independence for relative bipolarisation measurement. Ecineq Working Paper Series, 420.
Wehrens, R., & Buydens, L. M. C. (2007). Self- and super-organising maps in R: The kohonen package. Journal of Statistical Software, 21(5), 1–19.
Wolfson, M. (1994). When inequalities diverge. The American Economic Review, 84(2), 353–358.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix 1: Computing Evaluation Functions on Migrants’ Data
In this Appendix, we describe step-by-step the implementation of the posetic evaluation procedure on the migrants’ data and the computation of the evaluation functions which assign poverty and fragility scores to statistical units. Below, we focus on the main logic of the posetic procedure; technical and mathematical details can be found in Fattore (2016) and Fattore and Arcagni (2016).
1. Building the Poverty and Fragility posets To build the evaluation spaces of poverty and fragility, the first step is to cast the data into poset terms. A configuration \(\varvec{p}=(p_1,p_2,p_3,p_4)\) of scores on the four poverty attributes considered in the paper is called poverty profile. The set \(\varPi\) of \(5\times 3\times 3\times 4=180\) poverty profiles generated by taking all the combinations of attributes’ scores comprises all of the possible deprivation configurations, given the input multi-indicator system. Two poverty profiles \(\varvec{p}_a\) and \(\varvec{p}_b\) can be ordered in terms of deprivation, only if either all the scores of \(\varvec{p}_a\) are not higher than those of \(\varvec{p}_b\) or viceversa; in this case, \(\varvec{p}_a\) and \(\varvec{p}_b\) are called comparable. On the contrary, if \(\varvec{p}_a\) and \(\varvec{p}_b\) comprise so-called conflicting scores (e.g. if \(p_{a1}<p_{b1}\) and \(p_{b2}<p_{a2}\)), then they cannot be ordered and are called incomparable. The set \(\varPi\) is thus turned into a partially ordered set \((\varPi ,\unlhd )\), the Poverty poset, where \(\unlhd\) is a partial order relation defined by:
The poset \(\varPi\) has a bottom, or minimum, profile (1111), representing the worst deprivation configuration, and a top, or maximum, profile (5334), which represents the best situation. The analogous construction on the fragility attributes defines the Fragility poset\(\varPhi\), which comprises \(6\times 2\times 2\times 2=48\) profiles and has (1111) and (6222) as bottom and top profiles, respectively. The Fragility poset is depicted in Fig. 6, as a Hasse diagram (the Hasse diagram of the bigger Poverty poset is displayed in "Appendix 2").
2. Poverty and fragility thresholds Posets \(\varPi\) and \(\varPhi\) represent the spaces of poverty and fragility (notice that both of the posets may comprise profiles not realized in the data). To turn them into evaluation devices, poverty and fragility thresholds must be set in them. Explicitly, we identify a subset \(\pi _{\ell }\) of mutually incomparable profiles (a so-called antichain), representing achievement configurations “on the edge” of deprivation, so that any profiles in \(\pi _{\ell }\) or below an element of \(\pi _{\ell }\) (i.e. profiles in the so-called downset of \(\pi _{\ell }\)) are identified as deprived. Dually, we identify an antichain \(\pi _u\) composed of profiles representing configurations “on the edge” of well-being, so that profiles in \(\pi _{u}\) or above an element of \(\pi _{u}\) (i.e. profiles in the so-called upset of \(\pi _{u}\)) are identified as completely non-deprived.Footnote 7 Based on the lower and upper thresholds, \(\pi _{\ell }\) and \(\pi _{u}\), poverty profiles are then classified in three subsets: the subset of deprived profiles (on or below \(\pi _{\ell }\)), the subset of non-deprived profiles (on or above \(\pi _u\)) and the subset of ambiguously deprived profiles (configurations not belonging to the two other classes). The proper selection of the thresholds is clearly crucial in view of evaluation. In this study, as stated in previous paragraphs, the lower poverty threshold reduces to just one profile and has been set to \(\pi _{\ell }=3221\) (i.e. Living arrangement = “Living at the workplace”and Economic aid = “Kindship’s aid”and Medical treatment renunciation = “Return to the country of origin for medical treatment”and “Income belonging to the first quartile”). The non-deprivation threshold is instead set as \(\pi _u=4333\) (i.e Living arrangement = “Tenant alone or with family”and Economic aid = “No aid”and Medical treatment renunciation = “No renunciation”and “Income belonging to the third quartile”).
Lower and upper thresholds \(\phi _{\ell }\) and \(\phi _u\) are similarly set in the Fragility poset (see Fig. 6), namely as \(\phi _{\ell }=(3122, 3221)\) (i.e. Working dynamics = “Run into instability or persistent precariousness” and Legal status = “Illegal”and Dependent family in country of origin = “No”and One-income family = “No”; or Working dynamics = “Run into instability or persistent precariousness” and Legal status = “Legal”and Dependent family in country of origin = “No”and One-income family = “Yes”) and to \(\phi _{u}=3222\) (i.e. Working dynamics = “Run into instability or persistent precariousness” and Legal status = “Legal”and Dependent family in country of origin = “No”and One-income family = “No”). The lower fragility threshold comprises two profiles, since alternative score configurations may well represent fragility conditions. The upper threshold, instead, is composed of a single profile which is the minimum profile to be above both the elements of \(\phi _{\ell }\). Table 7 reports the selected thresholds for both posets.
Hasse diagram of the Fragility poset \(\varPhi\). Two nodes \(\varvec{p}_a\) and \(\varvec{p}_b\) are connected by a downward path, if and only if \(\varvec{p}_a\lhd \varvec{p}_b\); nodes not connected by a downward path are incomparable. In green, non-deprived profiles (the lowest green profile represents the upper threshold \(\phi _u=3222\)). In red, profiles representing certainly fragile conditions, the two “highest” red profiles constitute the lower threshold \(\phi _{\ell }=(3122, 3221)\). (Color figure online)
3. Performing evaluation Lower and upper thresholds inject into the Poverty and the Fragility posets a minimum amount of exogenous information on deprivation that triggers the evaluation procedure, leading to the computation of two evaluation functions, namely the identification function \(idn(\cdot )\) and the (so-called, see Fattore 2016) relative severity function \(svr(\cdot )\). The first assigns to each poverty or fragility profile \(\varvec{p}\) an identification score, to be interpreted in a fuzzy spirit, i.e. as the membership degree of \(\varvec{p}\) to poverty or to fragility; it assumes value 0 on profiles on or above the upper threshold, value 1 on profiles on or below the lower threshold and values in (0, 1), on all of the other profiles. When different from 0, the evaluation score can be complemented with a severity score, measuring the “depth” of deprivation or fragility. The identification score is computed based on a fundamental property of finite posets, i.e. that they are “equivalent” (see Fattore 2016 for a precise formulation) to the set of their linear extensions. These are linear orders obtained by resolving the incomparabilities of the input poset, in all possible ways; on each linear extension, profiles are either above or on/below the threshold and so can be classified as deprived (1) or non-deprived (0) in a binary way. Counting the fraction of linear extensions classifying a specified profile as deprived, one gets its deprivation score (see Fig. 7 for a simple example, taken from Fattore (2016)); in formulas, writing \(idn_{\ell }(\varvec{p})\) for the identification score of profile \(\varvec{p}\) in linear extension \(\ell\), \(idn(\varvec{p})\) for the final identification score of profile \(\varvec{p}\) and \(\varOmega\) for the set of linear extensions of the input poset (either the poverty or the fragility one), we have:
On a linear extension \(\ell\), it is also possible to measure the distance between a deprived profile \(\varvec{p}\) (in \(\ell\)) and the non-deprived profile nearest to it (in \(\ell\)), as the number of edges between them, in the Hasse diagram of \(\ell\). By averaging such distances over \(\varOmega\), one gets the severity score of \(\varvec{p}\), which is then normalized, dividing it by the highest severity score in the poset (which, in this case, is that of the bottom profile). Figure 8 depicts the identification and severity functions for both the Poverty and the Fragility profiles. As it can be seen, the identification functions resemble a logistic shape, although they get to assume both values 0 and 1. Similar comments can be given for the severity functions which are, however, more “linear” since, by construction, they get value 1 only on the bottom profile. It is important to realize that both evaluation functions are computed based on the thresholds and the structure of the partial order relation, with no aggregation of input ordinal scores; evaluation scores, in fact, are extracted directly from the network of comparabilities/incomparablities defining the posets (details can be found in Fattore 2016).
Hasse diagrams of the product of linear orders \((1-2-3)\) and \((1-2)\) and of its five linear extensions. In gray, completely deprived profiles; bold circles represent threshold profiles. Profiles classified as completely deprived in the poset on the left are those which are classified as deprived in any linear extension on the right, namely profile 31, 21, 12, 11 (which thus have deprivation score equal to 1). Profiles 32, which is the top of the poset, is classified as non-deprived in any linear extension and thus its deprivation score is 0. Profile 22 is classified as deprived by two linear extensions out of five, so its deprivation score is 2 / 5
The identification and severity scores of a profile are finally assigned to each statistical unit sharing that achievement configuration. Since the datasets present some missing values, some statistical units cannot be assigned to a specific poverty or fragility profile, but can be only assigned to a subset of the respective poset (Fattore 2016). As a result, these profiles get associated intervals of identification and severity scores, since their true scores are in between those of the bottom and the top of the subposet they are assigned to. Once each statistical unit has been assessed in terms of identification and severity, score distributions and overall indicators can be computed (possibly with intervals due to missing observations), in the spirit of the Head Count Ratio or Poverty Gap (Alkire and Foster 2011), and one can proceed to the socio-economic analysis of the results.
Appendix 2: Methodological Innovation
In this section, we describe how the posetic procedure formalized in Fattore (2016) has been modified, in order to allow for the lower and the upper poverty thresholds to be set independently of each other. The text below is more technical than the rest of the paper and is meant to complete it.
In the original procedure, setting the lower threshold implicitly sets the upper one to the antichain generating the intersection of the upsets of the lower threshold elements, in formulas:
(where \(\varvec{p}\!\uparrow\) is the upset of element \(\varvec{p}\)); in fact, the identification function equals 0 on all and only the profiles which are “greater than” all of the profiles in \(\pi _{\ell }\). A profile scored 0 by the identification function is certainly non-deprived, but in general this need not mean it represents a “full well-being” condition. Since in the present study we want the upper threshold to really identify well-being conditions, the set of profiles scored 0 by the identification function must be properly restricted. In practice, we want that the lower and the upper thresholds can be set independently of each other and, at the same time, we want the resulting identification function to be consistent with both of them. To this goal, one must change the structure of the input (from now on, called basic) partial order itself, in such a way that in the new poset the chosen upper threshold will be again the intersection of the elements of the lower threshold (this way, the identification function computed running the procedure described in "Appendix 1" will be necessarily consistent with the thresholds). To be practical, there are two main cases:
-
1.
In the basic poset, \(\pi _u\) comprises \(\bigcap _{\varvec{p}\in \pi _{\ell }}\varvec{p}\!\uparrow\), i.e. some other profiles, in addition to those in \(\cap _{\varvec{p}\in \pi _{\ell }}\varvec{p}\!\uparrow\) (in the original poset), are declared to be “non-deprived” by the analyst. In this case, the poset must be modified by inserting an edge between the corresponding nodes in the Hasse diagram, in such a way that each element of \(\pi _u\) is made greater than all of the elements of \(\pi _{\ell }\) (getting what is technically called an extension of the basic poset).
-
2.
In the basic poset, \(\pi _u\) is in the upset of \(\bigcap _{\varvec{p}\in \pi _{\ell }}\varvec{p}\!\uparrow\), i.e. some of the profiles declared as “non-deprived” in the basic poset, are now considered as partly deprived. This is the case of the present paper and the solution is more subtle than in the previous case. In fact, here no simple changes to the partial order structure solves the problem. The point can be illustrated as follows. If a profile \(\varvec{p}\), greater than each element of \(\pi _{\ell }\) in the basic poset, is now to be considered as partly deprived, this means that some other “latent attribute”(i.e. some other implicit ordering criterion) is involved in the definition of the evaluation space. Informally, the profiles “lack” some attributes that would make incomparable some profiles that, in the basic poset, are actually comparable. Clearly, it is not possible to explicit such attributes, so the only way to modify the poset, based on the previous assumption, is to introduce exogenously an additional profile, to set it as a part of \(\pi _{\ell }\) and to make it incomparable with the profiles which must be made partly deprived. This way, \(\pi _u=\cap _{\varvec{p}\in \pi _{\ell }}\varvec{p}\!\uparrow\) comprises only the desired profiles and the resulting identification function is consistent with the thresholds. Notice that inserting the exogenous profile is the “minimum modification to the basic poset” achieving the desired result; form this point of view, no arbitrary modifications are made to the input poset, since the introduction of the new profile is the “essential” implication of the setting of \(\pi _u\). This is an important point: in the posetic procedure, all of the exogenous information on evaluation criteria (e.g. the social value system assumed by the analyst or by the policy maker) must be turned into modifications of the input poset (addition of edges, insertion of profiles and setting of the thresholds). As a result, the poset representing the evaluation space of migrants’ deprivation, in the present paper, has the shape depicted in Fig. 9. This is the new input to the evaluation procedure described in "Appendix 1", producing the results discussed in the main text.
Migrants’ deprivation poset, modified as explained in "Appendix 2". Notice that the added profile (LT) is part of the lower threshold and that only the minimum number (i.e. here 1) of edges between it and other profiles have been inserted, so as that \(\pi _u=\cap _{\varvec{p}\in \pi _{\ell }}\varvec{p}\!\uparrow\) (in red, profiles on or below \(\pi _{\ell }\); in green, profiles on or above \(\pi _u\)). (Color figure online)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Arcagni, A., Barbiano di Belgiojoso, E., Fattore, M. et al. Multidimensional Analysis of Deprivation and Fragility Patterns of Migrants in Lombardy, Using Partially Ordered Sets and Self-Organizing Maps. Soc Indic Res 141, 551–579 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-018-1856-9
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-018-1856-9